Biofuels Markets and Policy: 20th Anniversary of the farmdoc Project
This is the sixth in a series of articles celebrating the 20th anniversary of farmdoc. A list of all nine articles in the series and authors can be found at the end of this article.
When the farmdoc project started in 1999 biofuels markets and policy were barely on the radar screen. However, production and use of biofuels in the U.S. grew very rapidly starting around 2005 due to a combination of factors. Two factors stand out: i) the large increase in real crude oil prices through 2008, and ii) implementation of the Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS), first in 2005 and then amended in 2007. The increase in crude oil prices is crucial as it made biofuels more competitive in the marketplace and led to a political reaction that spurred the passage of the RFS legislation through the U.S. Congress. The RFS mandates have been highly controversial, particularly in the petroleum refining sector, and subject to almost continuous legal challenge. Regardless, biofuels rose to become an important driver of prices in grain and oilseed markets. If one wanted to understand price dynamics in grain and oilseed markets since 2005, you had to understand what was going on in biofuel markets. The farmdoc team has played a leading role in understanding the complex interplay between biofuels policy and markets and the implications for grain and oilseed markets. The purpose of this article is to review key developments in biofuels markets and policy since 2005 and highlight the important contributions made by the farmdoc team to better understanding the implications for agricultural markets.
The RFS
We start with a review of the RFS, since this policy is central to understanding the evolution of biofuels production and use. The RFS was established by the Energy Policy Act of 2005 and was substantially expanded as part of the Energy Independence and Security Act (EISA) of 2007. The 2005 statute is generally referred to as “RFS1” and the 2007 statute as “RFS2.” Since its inception, the program has been administered by the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). The RFS2 statute required the EPA to establish volume requirements for four categories of biofuels for each year from 2008 through 2022: cellulosic biofuel, biomass-based diesel, total advanced biofuel (which includes biomass-based diesel), and renewable fuel (referred to as conventional ethanol here). The difference between the total advanced mandate and the total of the cellulosic and biodiesel mandate is referred to as the undifferentiated advanced mandate and can be satisfied by a combination of qualified advanced biofuels. Conventional biofuels are generally assumed to be corn-based ethanol but this is actually not explicitly required by the RFS legislation. Instead, corn-based ethanol generally has been the cheapest alternative for this category that also meets the environmental requirements of the RFS. The conventional biofuels mandate is referred to as the conventional ethanol mandate for the remainder of this article in order to be consistent with the most common term for this particular RFS mandate.
Figure 1 shows the statutory RFS volume standards from the 2007 legislation. The basic logic behind the standards was to rely almost entirely on “first generation” conventional ethanol in the early years and then transition to greater reliance on “second generation” advanced cellulosic ethanol. This is seen in the cap on conventional ethanol at 15 billion gallons starting in 2015 and the increase in cellulosic from 3 billion gallons in 2015 to 16 billion gallons in 2022. The total RFS mandate for biofuels maxes out in 2022 at 36 billion gallons. Note that the biodiesel mandate was established as a minimum of one billion gallons per year from 2012 through 2022, with larger amounts subject to EPA approval.
The mandated targets for cellulosic biofuels were very aggressive from the outset given that industrial-scale production was virtually non-existent at the time RFS2 was passed in 2007. While several plants have been built in the last decade, cellulosic ethanol production has struggled to reach a few million gallons. The vast bulk of what has been produced in this category is actually captured landfill gas in liquid form, which qualifies as a cellulosic biofuel due to the breakdown of paper lignin in landfills. The low production totals from all sources has caused the EPA to use its RFS waiver authority to write down the cellulosic mandate to very low levels relative to statutory levels each year to date. The total advanced biofuel mandate has also been written down in conjunction with the write down in the cellulosic mandate.
The Blend Wall
The E10 blend wall is the main reason that the RFS became so contentious. This issue arose because regulation in the U.S. has traditionally limited the ethanol content of gasoline blends to a maximum of 10 percent by volume. Consequently, the theoretical maximum amount of ethanol that can be consumed is 10 percent of total gasoline consumption. At the time the RFS was passed in 2007, it was commonly projected that U.S. gasoline consumption by 2015 would be 150 billion gallons. So, it is no surprise that the cap on the conventional ethanol mandate in 2015 was set to 15 billion gallons, exactly 10 percent of projected gasoline consumption. The problem is that actual gasoline consumption began falling almost as soon as the RFS was passed due to the combined effects of high real crude oil prices and the onset of the Great Recession. This meant that by 2013 the conventional ethanol mandate as specified in the RFS statute began to surpass the E10 blend wall.
Understanding what happens when the conventional ethanol mandate exceeds the E10 blend wall requires some understanding about how compliance under the RFS works. Obligated parties under the RFS are refiners and importers of gasoline and diesel. On annual basis, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) issues rulemakings about the volume of biofuels that each party must demonstrate is blended into final surface transportation fuel for that calendar year. Compliance is demonstrated by turning in to the EPA tradeable credits known as the Renewable Identification Numbers, or RINs for short. A RIN is created when a biofuel is produced and travels with the fuel as it moves through the supply chain. Obligated parties can obtain RINs by blending biofuels themselves or buying the credits from non-obligated parties.
As shown in Figure 2, the price of D6 ethanol RINs exploded in early 2013 as the conventional ethanol mandate exceeded the E10 blend wall for the first time. In a matter of months, the price of ethanol RINs went from a few cents to nearly $1.50 per gallon. While there have been many charges of manipulation to explain the price explosion, and subsequent RIN price volatility, there is actually a simple explanation. The RFS contains a “nesting” feature whereby advanced biofuel RINs, principally biodiesel, can be used to not only meet the biodiesel and advanced mandates but also the conventional ethanol mandate if need be. So, when the ethanol mandate began to exceed the blend wall the gap between the two had to be filled by something besides corn-based ethanol, and that something was biodiesel. In essence, biodiesel became the marginal gallon for filling the conventional ethanol mandate and ethanol RINs began closely tracking the much, much more expensive price of D4 biodiesel RINs.
Starting in 2013, the equivalent of political trench warfare broke out between petroleum refiners and biofuel producers. On one side, refiners and their political allies argued that the “RFS was broken” and that the dramatic increase in RINs prices was substantially harming their operating profits. On the other side, biofuels and agricultural groups argued that the RFS was intended by Congress to be a technology forcing program and that the high RIN price reflected the unwillingness of the petroleum refining industry to make the investments that would lower the cost of breaching the blend wall via higher ethanol blends such as E15 and E85.
Much like the trench warfare of World War I, the years since 2013 have seen an ebbing and flowing of which side had the upper hand in the political battle over the RFS. For example, the Obama Administration EPA cut the conventional ethanol mandate in 2014-2016 a total of 2.24 billion gallons under pressure from refiners. The EPA’s authority to make these cuts was immediately challenged by biofuel and agricultural groups, and in July 2017 a U.S. Federal Appeals Court ruled against the EPA. More recently, the Trump Administration EPA granted an unprecedented number of small refinery waivers (SREs) for the 2016-2018 compliance years. The SREs were granted retroactively, which effectively cut the RFS mandates by a total of 4.05 billion gallons. A firestorm of protest erupted from biofuel and agricultural groups, which continues to the present. Numerous efforts have been made in recent years to reconcile the interests of the two sides in implementing the RFS to no avail.
farmdoc Contributions
The farmdoc team had a unique opportunity to help write the “first draft” on the economics of biofuel markets and policy because everything was so new. Some highlights in this regard include:
- Ethanol and biodiesel plant profitability: Early on, representative models of ethanol and biodiesel plants were developed and used to track production profits. This led to further analysis of the factors driving changes in profitability over time, as well as analysis of such issues as the shut-down price of ethanol plants as the price of corn increased. The profit estimates now published at least annually serve as a widely-used benchmark.
- Ethanol demand and the RFS: When the RFS was first implemented there was limited understanding of the nature of the demand for ethanol. This issue came to a head in 2012 when the U.S. experienced a historically severe drought in the Corn Belt and corn production was curtailed dramatically. Many argued that the RFS conventional ethanol mandate should be waived under these circumstances. Our analysis was among the first to show that waiving the mandate would not necessarily reduce ethanol use because ethanol was a competitive component of the gasoline blend due to its octane value. In other words, gasoline blenders would continue to use ethanol up to the E10 blend wall so long as it was priced at or below the price of gasoline.
- Biodiesel demand and the RFS: A major question regarding the implementation of the RFS mandates emerged once the conventional ethanol mandate began to exceed the E10 blend wall in 2013. Specifically, what was the least cost alternative for obligated parties when filling the gap between the conventional ethanol mandate and the E10 blend wall? Most of the discussion of this issue centered on expanding the use of higher ethanol blends, such as E15 and E85. Our analysis cast doubt on the feasibility of expanding the use of higher ethanol blends and indicated that biodiesel was more likely to fill the conventional gap. With rising mandate levels over time, this implied that the demand for biodiesel would rise to previously unheard of levels. This also had the crucial implication that demand pressure from rising RFS mandates, once ethanol use reached the E10 blend wall, would be felt in oilseed markets rather than the corn market. The role of biodiesel as the “marginal gallon” in filling the gaps in the RFS is now a generally accepted assumption in modelling the impact of the RFS on biofuel and grain markets.
- Economics of RIN pricing: When RIN prices exploded in 2013 there was virtually no analytical foundation on RIN pricing to help understand what was driving the prices so high. The key insight we provided was based on the observation that biodiesel was the marginal gallon (least cost) for filling the gap between the conventional mandate and the E10 blend wall. This meant that whenever the conventional mandate exceeded the blend wall the price of a D6 ethanol RIN equaled to the price of D4 biodiesel RIN. When the conventional mandate was below the blend wall, D6 RIN prices would decouple from D4 RIN prices and return to being determined by E10 blending economics, which typically meant a D6 price of only a few cents. Much of the volatility D6 ethanol RIN prices over time could be traced back to changing market expectations of the likelihood of being in either state. This meant that RIN price volatility could be explained by the “fundamentals” rather than market manipulation or speculation.
- Biodiesel supply: When biodiesel is the marginal gallon (least cost) for filling the gaps in the RFS mandates the characteristics of the biodiesel supply curve play a key role in setting the level of all RIN prices. We provided some of the first empirical estimates of the biodiesel supply curve by taking advantage of unique market circumstances when the biodiesel tax credit expired at the end of a calendar year. The identified curves revealed that the biodiesel supply elasticity was much higher than previously suspected. This had the further implication that increasing the demand for biodiesel as RFS mandates increased would not pressure biodiesel and biodiesel feedstock prices as sharply as many feared.
- SREs and demand destruction: A major controversy has swirled around a seemingly obscure provision of the RFS that allows small refineries to be exempted from mandated volume requirements. The policy of the EPA in recent years has been to issue large numbers of small refinery waivers (SREs) retroactively but not adjust the percentage standards to reflect these waivers. The result is in an effective across-the-board cut in mandated volumes. The distribution of the reductions on the physical demand for different biofuels has been hotly debated. Our analysis shows little impact on the physical demand for ethanol because the vast majority of ethanol in the U.S. is consumed in the form of E10 and ethanol generally has been price competitively in the E10 gasoline blend. The bulk of the demand destruction of SREs has been borne by biodiesel because biodiesel is the marginal gallon for filling the gaps in the RFS mandates. We estimated that the economic value of this damage to the biodiesel industry has been in the billions of dollars.
Closing Thoughts
Understanding biofuels markets and policy has been an essential part of analyzing agricultural markets for much of the last 20 years. This has opened up study of topics unimagined two decades ago, such as RIN pricing and the supply of biodiesel. The farmdoc team has played an important role in helping understand the complex interplay between biofuels policy and markets and the implications for grain and oilseed markets. We look forward to continuing this tradition in the future.
farmdoc daily 20th Anniversary Celebration Series
Irwin, S. “farmdoc at 20: How Did We Get Here and What Have We Learned?” farmdoc daily (9):163, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 3, 2019.
Hubbs, T. “Grain Price Outlook: farmdoc Twentieth Anniversary.” farmdoc daily (9):164, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 4, 2019.
Sherrick, B. and G. Schnitkey. “farmdoc and farmdoc daily Crop Insurance Contributions – 20 years and Counting.” farmdoc daily (9):165, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 5, 2019.
Coppess, J., C. Zulauf, N. Paulson and G. Schnitkey. “Farm Policy Perspectives: 20th Anniversary of the farmdoc Project.” farmdoc daily (9):166, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 6, 2019.
Schnitkey, G., D. Lattz, P. Ellinger, B. Sherrick and R. Batts. “Farm Management in farmdoc.” farmdoc daily (9):167, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 9, 2019.
Irwin, S. and D. Good. “Biofuels Markets and Policy: 20th Anniversary of the farmdoc Project.” farmdoc daily (9):168, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 10, 2019.
Baylis, K. and J. Coppess. “Farmdoc 20 Year Retrospective on Agricultural Trade (In Chart Form).” farmdoc daily (9):169, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 11, 2019.
Endres, A., D. Uchtmann and G. Hoff. “Law and Taxation: A Retrospective of 20 Years.” farmdoc daily (9):170, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 12, 2019.
Paulson, N. and B. Sherrick. “farmdoc and farmdoc daily: Farm Real Estate Markets – 20 Years and Growing.” farmdoc daily (9):171, Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, September 13, 2019.
Disclaimer: We request all readers, electronic media and others follow our citation guidelines when re-posting articles from farmdoc daily. Guidelines are available here. The farmdoc daily website falls under University of Illinois copyright and intellectual property rights. For a detailed statement, please see the University of Illinois Copyright Information and Policies here.